Copyright
(c) 1998 Tax Analysts
Tax
Notes
SEPTEMBER
28, 1998
DEPARTMENT: Special Reports
(SPR)
CITE: 80 Tax Notes
1603
HEADLINE: 80 Tax Notes 1603
- CORPORATE TAX SHELTERS, 1997 AND 1998.
(Section 6111) (Doc 98-29081 (11 pages))
AUTHOR: Johnson, Calvin H.
University of Texas
CODE: Section 6111
SUMMARY:
Professor Calvin Johnson notes that almost all corporate
decisions qualify as tax shelters under the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 and the
Internal Revenue Service Restructuring and Reform Act of 1998 since the
definition of corporate tax shelter is very broad.
Calvin Johnson is professor of law, University of Texas. This
report is based on a letter sent to the Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for
Tax Policy with respect to a prospective regulation project to be opened to
interpret the 'corporate tax shelter' provisions of the 1997 and 1998 tax
acts.
The 1997 and 1998 acts define a 'corporate tax shelter'as an
arrangement with a significant purpose to avoid or evade tax. The IRS has three
remedies under the acts for corporate shelters. There is an automatic 20
percent penalty on large tax underpayments. The privilege allowing the
corporation to prevent disclosures in civil litigation is narrower and does not
cover written communiciations with a nonattorney adviser. The shelter must be
preregistered with the IRS if there is a proprietary confidentiality agreement
and promoter fees are substantial. Johnson argues that almost all corporate
decisions qualify as tax shelters under the statutory definition, but that the
remedies provided are modest and appropriate to the seriousness of the
problem.
The author thanks Professors Michael Lang, David Weisbach, Mark
Gergen, and Keith Engel for helpful comments on an early draft.
________________________________________________________________________________
Table of Contents
I.
Broad Reach of the Statutory Definition. . . . . . . . . . . 1604
II.
Remedies Should Be Broad-Reaching. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1605
A. The 20 Percent Accuracy-Related
Penalty. . . . . . . . . 1606
B. Testimonial Privilege. . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . 1607
C. Registration With the IRS. . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . 1608
________________________________________________________________________________
1 In the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997 and the Internal Revenue
Service Restructuring and Reform Act of 1998, Congress adopted remedies to control
corporate 'tax shelters,' defining a shelter as a plan or arrangement for which
a significant purpose is avoidance or evasion of any tax. Falling within the
definition of 'tax shelter' means that (1) there is a 20 percent penalty on
corporate tax deficiencies should the IRS prevail on the merits, /1/ (2) there
is no privilege in tax litigation to prevent production of written
communications between the taxpayer and nonattorney tax adviser with respect to
the shelter, /2/ and (3) the shelter, if offered under a proprietary
confidentiality arrangement and for aggregate promoter fees of over $100,000,
must be preregistered with the IRS and its tax advantages disclosed. /3/
Treasury is in the process of formulating proposed regulations under the new
corporate- shelter provisions, but nothing has been issued.
2 The definition of corporate tax shelter in the 1997 and 1998
acts is extraordinarily broad, even automatic. A corporate tax shelter is
defined as an arrangement with a significant purpose to reduce tax. For better
or worse, tax reduction is a significant issue in almost every corporate
decision. Reduction of tax is a significant purpose, as long as corporate rates
are significant, because corporations are organized to maximize after-tax
income available to shareholders. The
remedies, however, are appropriate, even modest, for the problem of
corporate underreporting of tax, even if every corporate action is defined
automatically as a tax shelter. The Treasury regulations defining corporate tax
shelter cannot and should not narrow the very broad range to which the remedies
apply, as determined by the plain meaning of the statute.
________________________________________________________________________________
I. Broad Reach of the
Statutory Definition
________________________________________________________________________________
3 The statutory definition of 'corporate tax shelter' is broad.
The new definition in the 1997 and 1998 acts is that a shelter is a plan or
arrangement for which a significant purpose is avoidance or evasion of any tax.
The definition applies to both avoidance and evasion of tax. Evasion has
historically referred to the illegal criminal motive and avoidance has
traditionally been used to describe legal tax minimization. /4/ 'Tax shelter'
under the new provisions thus covers both legal and illegal tax reduction.
4 A corporation is presumably a tax-reducing entity on every
occasion. A corporation is an enterprise organized for the profit of its
shareholders. /5/ It has a fiduciary duty to its shareholders to maximize its
after-tax income, so as to give shareholders the highest possible future
dividends and share price. Tax reduction and nontax motives are not alternative
or antagonistic paths. Taxes arise inevitably along the road from pretax income
to the after-tax income that benefits shareholders. Because pretax and tax
motives occur on the same road, a nontax or pretax motive does not negate a
tax- avoidance motive. The prime maxim of the discipline of economics is that
every actor maximizes its disposable return. For a corporation, that prime
maxim means that after-tax income for shareholders is always the purpose of
corporate actions and that every corporation reduces tax, to the full extent
allowed by law and civilization.
5 Corporate tax is almost always a significant fraction of the
ultimate corporate purpose. Congress chose the phrase 'significant purpose'
because it was a lower percentage than existing standards. Congress was vague
so that the language would stretch over varying views of different individual
members, but the term significant still has enough content to cover any
corporate planning that I know of. Significant is a lower percentage than 'the
principal purpose,' /6/ which means 'greater than 50 percent' and lower than
the standard, 'a principal purpose.' /7/ The article 'a' in the 'a principal
purpose' standard means, somewhat oxymoronically, that cases exist in which
there is more than one principal purpose, and given that, the smaller of two
principal purposes has to have a weight of 50 percent or less. If there are
three principal purposes, then the smallest principal purpose must have a
weight of one-third or less. 'A principal purpose,' accordingly, probably covers
down to under one-third. 'Significant' is even lower than 'a principal purpose'
and that means that significant is under one-third by enough to justify
adopting a new, unfamiliar standard. In accounting, an item usually becomes
material at a level of 5-10 percent, /8/ and significant seems to mean at least
material. Significant thus means some fraction well below 33 percent but
greater or equal to 5-10 percent.
6 Corporate taxes are almost a greater percentage than
'significant.' Corporations usually face marginal tax rates of 34 percent or 35
percent. Even the next bracket, 25 percent, which comes in at corporate taxable
income of $50,000, seems to be higher than 'significant.' Even for corporations
with net operating losses currently, taxes still can be saved in the future by
action now. There must then be a time-value-of-money discount of the statutory
tax rate to reflect the fact that the corporation has net operating losses to
protect it from tax for some years and that current tax deductions will save
tax only after the NOLs are consumed. The time- value discount, however, can be
quite modest. Even with net operating losses, taxes will usually represent a
significant fraction of income. To show that a corporation did not take into account significant tax, a
corporation would have to show that it had an imbecility that would mean we
should not let it out on the streets on weekdays, and that would be hard to
prove with credibility. For better or worse, corporate taxes are a significant
aspect of almost every corporate decision.
7 The statutory standard cannot have been meant to be a
subjective standard. Corporations are artificial entities, so that even if we
had invented brain-wave readers by now, those brain- readers would not register
anything when aimed at a corporate taxpayer. Minds, certainly fictitious things
like corporate minds, are like Jell-O. To paraphrase the Green Berets, if
enough tax is at stake, 'their hearts and minds will follow.' Tax cannot be
built on so weak a foundation. 'A matter so real as tax,' Judge Friendly tells
us, 'must depend on objective realities, not on varying subjective beliefs. . .
.' /9/ Corporations can be understood to have purposes, as economic entities,
because they are organized to reduce tax and maximize after-tax income for
their shareholders. But it is silly to inquire into actual intent of a
corporation that is entirely a nonactual, fictitious entity, once it is given
that corporate tax rates are at a significant level.
8 The conference committee report on the 1998 act stated that
the conferees did not understand that the promotion of tax shelters was part of
the routine relationship between a tax practitioner and a client so that the
tax shelter limitations would not adversely affect such routine relationships.
/10/ Reading the language charitably, that is usually true. It is not good or
routine tax practice to give the corporation advice that turns out to be wrong
nor routine for the lawyer to keep ownership of the tax plan. Routine tax
advice, one might hope, does not recommend that the corporation play the tax
lottery. The object of a Treasury regulation, however, is not to parse or
defend the statement of the conferees. The statutory definition -- an
arrangement with a significant purpose to reduce tax -- is the standard in the
bill that Congress passed and the president signed. Conference language, by
contrast, is the work of staffers, usually under lobbyists' influence, who are
trying to amend or override the statute with spin control. As Justice Scalia
has well reminded us, the conference language is not the language to which the
sovereignty of a statute attaches. /11/ Thus while Treasury should always be
diplomatic to tax conferees, the statute on its face gives the regulation
writers no occasion to worry about or interpret what 'routine tax practice'
might be.
________________________________________________________________________________
II. Remedies Should Be
Broad-Reaching
________________________________________________________________________________
9 The problem addressed by the new corporate shelter provisions,
underreporting of corporate tax, is not a trivial concern. Ours is a
self-reporting tax system that relies primarily on accurate reporting of tax
due on tax returns. Ideally, every corporation would report on its return the
amount of tax truly due under law, as would be determined by the final decision
of a competent court after competent, comprehending audit. Tax law, as finally
determined by a court, makes a sounder tax system than the ersatz systems
created by the corporations themselves under conditions of underenforcement. A
self-reporting system in which corporations report the correct amount of tax is
also far better than a system that would require a full audit and litigation
for every tax dollar. But a self-reporting system is not the same thing as an
'honor' or voluntary system for tax, and it does need some support from
economic incentives to make it work.
10 It has to be in the economic interest of a corporation to
self-assess tax accurately. Corporations do not ordinarily respond very well to
pleas for patriotism or for loyalty to the integrity of the tax system.
Corporations plausibly do have duties to the United States -- to US. A
certificate of incorporation is not a license to shuck all law and clothing and
run amok across the prairies. Still the duties of a corporation to the nation
are not strongly developed. Relying on anything less than economic incentives
to get corporations to report tax accurately may well be nothing but
sanctimonious cant. /12/ If Congress wants corporations to follow the laws as
passed, it will need to enforce the law. That will mean that errors in
reporting tax need to bear a penalty, relative to accurate reporting.
11 Corporate tax aggressiveness seems to be increasing.
According to available statistics, the gap between what large corporations owe
and what they pay is large /13/ and growing fast. /14/ The figures available to
the IRS, however, are also now so out of date that its statistics are unreliable, /15/ so that the IRS has
been blinded from even assessing the size of the cloud. Still, knowlegeable
observers do find that corporations are increasingly depending on shelters.
/16/ The investment bankers and Big Five accounting firms are pushing corporate
tax planning competitively to the very edge. Tax law was once written for a
community that shared a faith in the underlying principles of tax law. The 1939
code, for example, stated tax due in terms of a few general principles, with
the understanding that taxpayers and government would work out the consequences
of the principles, with full respect, as the issues came up. That approach
would never work under current norms. Audit rates are too low to be even a
credible bluff. Even after audit, the disparity between private and IRS tax
practitioner salaries has grown so large that the IRS staff is always in the
dark, undertrained, undermotivated and stretched far too thin in any tax
controversy. Tax planning has grown so aggressive that every word or provision
that can be misunderstood is creatively misinterpreted to yield the least
possible tax. No one seems to be reporting by looking to what the outcome would
truly be if a competent court decided the issue.
12 Perhaps loopholes are inevitable:
________________________________________________________________________________
In this arms race betweeen taxpayers
eager to hold onto as much
as they can and tax law eager to stop
them, one should bet on
the taxpayers. . . . Like disobedient
children taxpayers have a
great deal of ingenuity, a natural bent
for coming up with new
and not-yet-forbidden ways of doing the
sort of thing the rules
seem to be trying to forbid. They also
have a taste for doing
just that. These talents and inclinations
predictably outrun the
rulemakers' ability to define prohibited
behavior with
precision. The legal system is, to some
degree helpless. /17/
________________________________________________________________________________
The only reason why
Treasury should not give up in full is that tax must somehow be collected. If
tax is a game, Treasury has to win it.
13 Given the problem, the consequences triggered by falling
within the definition of corporate tax shelter are quite modest. The function
of the remedies is (a) to give inducements to corporations to report their tax
accurately, as defined by the real decision that a court would reach, (b) to
get evidence from advisers that would allow the courts to reach truth and
justice, and (c) to give the IRS a chance, a road map, to contest
budget-busting corporate schemes early in their life. For all three remedies,
the broad definition of corporate shelter, provided by the significant purpose
test, seems fully justified.
A. The 20 Percent Accuracy-Related Penalty
14 The first consequence of falling within the definition of a
'corporate shelter' is that standards of reporting get raised for the purposes
of the 20 percent substantial understatement penalty. Section 6662 collects a
number of civil accuracy-related, nondeductible penalties, each for 20 percent
of tax underpayments. Subsection (d) of section 6662 imposes the 20 percent
penalty on substantial understatements of tax, defining 'substantial' for
corporations as tax underpayments that are larger than 10 percent of tax
properly due and also larger than $10,000. In general, taxpayers can avoid the
subsection (d) substantial understatement penalty if (1) there was 'substantial
authority' for the taxpayer's position on the tax return /18/ or (2) if the
taxpayer adequately discloses the position on the return or an attachment and
the position on the return had a reasonable basis for it. /19/ In 1997 Congress
amended the substantial understatement rules of section 6662(d) for corporate
shelters. Falling within the definition of a corporate tax shelter now means
that the defenses based on substantial authority and disclosure of a reasonable
position are not available. /20/ An arrangement is a corporate tax shelter if
there is a significant purpose to reduce tax and, as explained in the last
section, that happens automatically. Thus the 20 percent penalty is automatic
if the corporation tax return position ultimately loses and the underpayment is
substantial.
15 A 20 percent penalty imposed automatically if the corporation
loses in a substantial tax case is a very good idea. The corporate behavior you
want to encourage is reporting and paying over the amount of tax that is due as
finally determined by a court. The behavior you want to discourage is reporting
and paying over less than the amount that is ultimately determined to be due.
Giving a corporation an immunity from penalty if it has a reasonable basis or substantial
authority for its reporting position will mean that the corporation will not
try hard enough to predict real outcomes of the case. Giving the corporation
credit for reasonable basis or substantial authority is a bit like scoring
football games by the number of good tries or reasonable efforts. Scoring by
touchdowns accomplished seems to encourage each side to try harder. Giving a
corporation credit for reasonable effort or substantial authority also means
that the corporations' lawyers and accountants will be looking for a good
excuse not to pay tax and will not try hard enough to be right. Giving a
corporation an immunity from tax penalty for reasonable basis or substantial authority does not give the
corporation an incentive to correct its errors.
16 A penalty that made it in the corporation's self-interest to
correct its errors would be an automatic penalty that would be very much higher
than 20 percent. Assume, for example, that a corporation underreports tax, as
tax would be finally determined, that there is a 50 percent chance of the
corporation being audited, a 50 percent chance of the auditor spotting the
error, a 50 percent chance of the auditor being able to articulate the issue
well enough to convince the IRS to go forward on the error, and a 50 percent
chance of the IRS prevailing eventually. That means that there is a 50
percent*50 percent*50 percent*50 percent or 1/16th chance of the IRS correcting
the reporting error. A corporation would win on the audit lottery by
underreporting its taxes, considering the law of averages for a 1/16th chance
of correction, only if there is an automatic penalty on a corporate error that
is 16 times the tax deficiency or 1,600 percent. /21/ The neutral penalty might
be lower than 1,600 percent. An auditor's ability to spot an issue might not be
independent of her ability to convince the IRS to go to court. On the other
side, the IRS does not usually get to audit 50 percent of returns and the
chances of its agents understanding the issue may be less than 50 percent, so
that the appropriate penalty to neutralize the incentive to make errors can
easily be much greater than 1,600 percent. Making the 20 percent penalty
automatic -- depending on outcome and not on 'substantial authority' or
'reasonable basis' or a similar 'good try' idea -- is a step in the right
direction if you want real tax law to be enforced. Even an automatic 20 percent
penalty, however, is quite modest in comparison to the penalty that would be
needed to take away the incentive for a corporation to make self-help errors on
its return.
B. Testimonial Privilege
17 Falling within the 'tax shelter' definition also means that a
corporate taxpayer cannot prevent written communications between the taxpayer
and its nonattorney tax advisers from being discovered in civil tax litigation.
The 1998 act enacted a new section 7525 to extend the common-law
attorney-client privileges to civil tax cases and administrative tax
proceedings in which it is not an attorney, but rather an accountant or
enrolled agent who gave the taxpayer the tax advice. /22/ Section 7525 does
not, however, extend the nondiscovery privilege to written communications
between corporation and adviser in connection with the promotion of or
participation in a corporate tax shelter. /23/ Since section 7525 defines
corporate tax shelter by cross-reference as an arrangement with a significant
purpose to reduce federal tax, /24/ the new privilege extension does not apply
to any corporate decision where the corporation faces significant tax. Section
7525 thus is one of those big-hat, no-cattle provisions, because the section
starts off with what might seem an important privilege, but then takes back the
privilege when the client is a corporation.
18 Loss of the section 7525 privilege does not mean very much.
The privilege is so riddled with exceptions, even in non-tax- shelter
arrangements, that it is worth slightly less than nothing. The privilege is
defined by reference to common law attorney-client privileges and the common-law
privilege is leaky and unreliable. The common-law privilege does not attach to
communications that really are incident to rendition of financial or accounting
services, to communications incident to rendering business advice, or to
communications incident to preparation of a tax return. /25/ The privilege is
easily waived. /26/ It may not apply where it is the promoter's general
promotional materials or projections that are sought and not confidential
information specific to the taxpayer. /27/
19 The extension of the privilege, moreover, on the face of the
statute does not apply to many kinds of legal proceedings where the outcomes
can be draconian. The extension of the privilege to nonattorneys does not apply
to civil litigation against nongovernment private parties, no matter how much
is at stake. It does not apply to nontax proceedings such as SEC disciplinary
proceedings, bank looting cases, or license revocation proceedings where a
whole career is at stake. It does not apply to criminal tax cases, where a
privilege might keep somebody out of jail. /28/ A privilege with so many
exceptions is about like having the confessional booth hooked up to the public
address system in the piazza, with the understanding that whenever something
juicy is said, the PA system will be switched on. Loss of such a privilege is
no loss at all. /29/
20 'A significant purpose to reduce tax' also just gets the
system back to the good policy decisions of traditional law. Denial of the
privilege for certified public
accountants is perfectly consistent with sound public policy. Public
accountants have always had a responsibility to the investing public to
disclose unpleasant facts about the corporation in the financial statements or
footnotes. The accounting firm that audits a corporation is a cop on the beat,
with no obligation to be the corporation's friend or keep its secrets. No
corporation should ever expect confidentiality from its certified public
accounting firm. /30/
21 The effect of a testimonial privilege, moreover, is to
prevent accurate but embarrassing facts from becoming known in court. The
traditional view, denying a privilege to accountants, reflected a wise judgment
that the strict confidentiality standards of the attorney-client privilege go too
far /31/ and should not be extended. The traditional view, denying the
privilege, holds that getting the right result is not just an important factor
in a tax case; the right result is the only purpose of the tax proceeding. If
all corporate decisions lose the privilege, that will merely reflect the wise
traditional judgment that honesty and accuracy still count.
22 The properly broad tax shelter exception will, however, still
leave some issues privileged from discovery. The tax shelter exception applies
only to 'written communications.' In this age of e-mail, that undoubtedly
applies to writing conveyed by electrons and to spreadsheets and projections,
written in numbers. Hopefully, the exception has a penumbra under which
litigators can ask a human being to explain what the writing means. The
exception, however, probably does not apply to tapes, so that if, for instance,
a famous-name- national-brokerage house gives a tape that is supposed to self-
destruct after the client hears it, then the tape is immune from discovery. If
anything, the privilege still available, even for corporate shelters, is too
broad.
23 Section 7525 also apparently has no effect on the traditional
attorney-client privilege, whatever the scope of that privilege, because it is
stated in terms of extension of attorney- client privilege. For an arrangement
that is a tax shelter, the section 7525 extender would not apply, but the
common-law attorney- client privilege would still be available, whatever its
uncertain scope.
C. Registration With the IRS
24 Falling within the 'tax shelter' definition finally affects
whether the arrangement must be registered with the IRS. Section 6111 provides
for registration of certain tax shelters with the IRS before the shelter is offered
for sale to any taxpayer. The registration statement must explain, for the
education of the IRS, the tax benefits of the shelter as represented to the
potential investors. /32/ The organizer must provide a list of taxpayers who
invested in the shelter and each investor must include on its tax return the
identification number assigned to the shelter.
25 The general purpose of section 6111 for corporate shelters is
to give the IRS an accurate road map about corporate deals that are especially
threatening at an early stage of their development. With a good road map from
the registration of the scheme, the IRS can decide what corporate tax returns
it should select for audit and it can instruct its auditors to focus in on the
real tax issues quickly and efficiently. The IRS can also use the registration
information to decide whether additional legislation or administrative action
is needed before the revenue losses get too out of hand. /33/ With a good road
map, the Treasury Department can issue notices announcing that it considers the
transaction to be abusive and that it will contest the claimed tax treatment on
audit and in court. Good notices often act like first-aid compresses, slowing
down the hemorrhaging revenue loss from an especially threatening scheme.
/34/
26 Even beyond the specific transaction in the registration, a
registration statement for tax shelters can prove to be an invaluable source of
education for the IRS and its auditing agents. A registration must explain the
tax benefits to the auditing agent just as the promoter was educating the
client. Education from one registration can be used against other deals. When a
number of registrations pile up, the IRS will have a large enough collection of
registration statements that it can see the woods as well as the trees and see
which shelters are truly threatening to the revenue base as a whole. The IRS
may well come back and seek legislation or other remedy, only after some time
and after a number of registered shelters of one kind have appeared in their
files.
27 Prior to the 1997 act, the only test as to whether the
shelter had to be registered was whether the ratio of tax deductions to cash
invested was greater than 2:1. An arrangement was defined to be a shelter that
had to be registered if at the end of any of the first five years, the
deductions generated were in excess of twice
the cash invested. /35/ The 1997 act added a new subsection (d) to
section 6111, requiring registration for large-fee arrangements subject to propriety
confidentiality agreements. /36/ Under new subsection 6661(d), an arrangement
must be registered if it (1) was sold under conditions of proprietary
confidentiality, (2) might generate more than $100,000 in aggregate promoter
fees and (3) had a significant purpose to reduce tax. Congress's decisions to
require preregistration are reasonable to the situation and Congress's
decisions are binding law, even if they are not so reasonable.
1. Proprietary confidentiality.
28 To be a tax shelter under the 1997 addition, an arrangement
must, first, be subject to a contract or understanding under which some
promoter other than the taxpayer has a proprietary interest in the arrangement
or can prohibit the taxpayer from disclosing the arrangement. An arrangement
has the required proprietary interest if someone other than the taxpayer owns
the arrangement (or any aspect of it). /37/ An arrangement also has the
required proprietary confidentiality, if the offeror tells potential investors
that the investor may not discuss or disclose the tax shelter or any
significant tax features of it to someone else. /38/
29 The theory behind subsection 6111(d) is that giving a
promoter intellectual property rights in an anti-tax scheme will create an
incentive that can do far too much damage to a sound tax system. There is a law
and economics literature arguing that giving intellectual property rights in an
idea to some person will lead to the maximum exploitation of the idea. The
owner with a proprietary right to exclude others from free use of the idea will
be able to charge a price for the idea and thus will have an incentive to
improve or perfect the idea and market it so as to maximize the output from the
idea. /39/ Ownership or confidentiality allows the tax adviser to go from the
careful custom-tailored tax planning of traditional law practice, pleasing one
customer at time, and into mass-marketed 'cookie cutter' tax planning in which
the tax adviser can keep using the same template for many different clients.
30 We do not, however, want to maximize the output from anti-
government plans. The output from an anti-tax arrangement is an assault on the
soundness and equity of the tax system and maximizing the output means maximum
assault on the system. Once the best tax system is destroyed by such plans, the
revenue system left after the assault will be far less even-handed and
equitable and will do far more damage to the economy per dollar of revenue
raised. Thus proprietary confidentiality is used as an indicator of potential
abuse. The good idea behind subsection 6111(d) is that if anyone claims an
exclusive property right in an anti-tax scheme, then he had better be required
to give the government a road map just to counteract the incentive he are
getting from property rights.
31 The proprietary confidentiality that is the target of new
section 6111(d) does not mean confidentiality that the corporate taxpayer
imposes on its tax attorney or other agents. An attorney is always prohibited
from disclosing a client's business, under the rules of professional
responsibility. An attorney may not discuss or disclose a client's business to
anyone but the client without the client's permission. /40/ The target of
section 6111(d), by contrast, is prohibitions of disclosure imposed on the
taxpayer by the tax attorney or adviser. The fear is that the nontaxpayer
promoter will market to many taxpayers to do maximal harm.
32 Proprietary anti-tax plans plausibly are a tell-tale sign of
abuse, although perhaps not as good an indicator of potential abuse as the 2:1
ratio of tax deductions to cash invested, which was the only definition of a
shelter under pre-1997 law. When shelter registration was first adopted in
1984, the 2:1 ratio was a very significant line. The top tax rate at the time
was 50 percent. A taxpayer who could deduct $2 in the 50 percent tax bracket
saved $1 tax, that is, an amount equal to the amount invested. If the tax
saving held up, the taxpayer would go forward into the arrangement for the tax
alone, even if the underlying activity was worthless ignoring tax. Shelters
with a ratio of 2:1 often meant that the taxpayer would disregard the
underlying nontax economics of the transaction. /41/ The 2:1 ratio was a telltale sign of a potentially very abusive
tax shelter because the taxpayer investor stopped caring about the underlying
economic reality of the transaction and it was a shelter that the IRS needed to
go after. It is hardly clear that the property rights in a proprietary
confidentiality arrangement are as potent an inducement toward abuse as the 2:1
ratio was. On the other hand, for the new subsection (d) proprietary
confidentiality shelters, in any event, unlike the old 2:1 ratio shelters,
there is also a substantiality requirement, that the promoters' fees exceed
$100,000. The ability to do 'cookie cutter' deals may be a strong incentive.
The $100,000 fee combined with proprietary ownership are together a signal that
there may be a clear and present danger.
33 If the registration road map turns out to be too useful to
the IRS, then it may well turn out that section 6111(d) will not generate any
material number of registrations. Promoters will instead just abandon their
claims to proprietary rights so that they do not have to disclose the tax
benefits to the IRS. The other requirements for falling under section 6111(d),
a significant purpose to reduce tax, and $100,000 in adviser's fees, are more
difficult to avoid. The suppression of proprietary confidentiality agreements,
however, may be an acceptable result, even though the opportunity to identify
aggressive tax plans is lost. The tax system will then not be subject to such
destructive attacks from cookie cutter shelters that promoters have property
rights in.
2. Large fees.
34 An arrangement needs
to be registered under new section 6111(d) only if it is an arrangement 'for
which the tax shelter promoters may receive fees in excess of $100,000 in
aggregate.' /42/ The size of the tax adviser's fees is not a bad tell-tale sign
of abuse. If we were to start afresh in defining the right scope for the
preregistration remedy, we would need to design a rule that would identify big
new loopholes, while exempting tax plans that the IRS cannot defeat under
current law and which Treasury would not want to ask Congress to defeat. Such a
screen separating big loopholes from well-settled tax avoidance is, however,
next to impossible to design. Suppose the statute, expressing its intent, just
said that big new loopholes have to be registered? How would you define a
loophole? Any screen enacted will have to rely on imperfect indicators. The
level of fees might well serve as an indicator of a new loophole because tax
advisers cannot charge high fees for well beaten or routine paths to tax reduction.
It does not take $100,000 to tell the client to buy municipal bonds.
35 Quite plausibly a fee of $100,000 is too low a number. /43/
Plausibly, the IRS needs first to have advanced warning on the budget-busting
arrangements that might result in half-billion-dollar tax deficiencies. The
IRS, first and foremost, needs to pick up half- billion-dollar corporate tax
deficiencies that might otherwise slip through the cracks. In the truly
budget-busting arrangements, the lawyers and accountants fees will be in excess
of $100,000. But Congress in its wisdom has defined the $100,000 fee level as
the level at which the IRS needs to get the advanced warning and the education
about the tax benefits that a preregistration with the IRS would provide. The
$100,000 statutory amount seems to be appropriately subject to the maxim that
'a statute drafted as meticulously as tax must be interpreted as a literal
expression of the taxing policy, leaving only the small interstices for
judicial interpretation.' /44/
36 The fact that $100,000 might have been set higher, however,
may carry some implications about how tough the IRS needs to be in aggregating
different clients to see if promoters receive $100,000 in aggregate. If all the
shelter promoter does is make a global replacement of name of the taxpayer in
the governing documents, then it seems that aggregation of fees from the
different clients should be automatic. On the other end of the spectrum, if a
lawyer specializes in real estate sales or equipment leases or ERISA plans and
does a lot of custom work for each client and each transaction, then the fact
that there are recurring patterns and even a set of master documents should not
mean that the lawyer's fees for her entire career should be aggregated. The regulations
might give a presumption that if half the writing is new for each client, then
it can be presumed that the fees from each client will not be aggregated to
reach $100,000.
37 The statute's use of promoter's fees aggregating $100,000
will, however, mean that there will be some clever planning to disaggregate
fees to different attorneys or accountants. If a $100,000 fee is paid to a firm
with 1,000 accountants, for example, one should expect to see claims that each
individual member received only a $100 share and that only transactions giving
more than a $100 million fee to the firm will be over the threshhold. Fees paid
to a single firm should automatically be aggregated.
3. Significant purpose to reduce tax.
38 Registration under section 6111(d) also requires that a
significant purpose of the plan or arrangement be for the evasion or avoidance
of tax. As it has been argued above, tax is always a significant consideration
in corporate decisions, whenever the tax rate is significant, so that the
significant purpose requirement will not serve to exempt any arrangements from
the registration requirement.
39 While the 'significant purpose' net sweeps very wide, it is
difficult to see how Congress could have written any more selective a test and
still kept the abuses within the net. Registration needs to reach the big
budget-busting corporate arrangements that pose a large enough threat to
corporate tax base that the IRS should be able to plan to meet them in advance.
It is, however, impossible to anticipate beforehand just from where the attack on the tax base will come.
The minds of tax planners are varied, fertile, and surprising. Take a look at
some of the billion- dollar-plus corporate schemes of the last few years. They
have almost nothing in common except for their ingenuity and their surprise:
________________________________________________________________________________
a. Converting corporate capital gain
into dividends.
Seagram Inc. claimed to save $ 1.5 billion
tax, by getting its
sale of Du Pont stock (to Du Pont)
treated as a dividend
(subject to 10.5 percent tax) instead of
capital gain (subject
to 35 percent tax) by creating an option
of nonmaterial value to
reacquire nonvoting Du Pont stock. Under
section 318(a)(4), an
option to acquire stock means that the
corporation still owns
the stock, no matter how immaterial the
value of the stock, so
that Seagram still literally owned the
stock under the
constructive ownership rules for
redemptions even after selling
the Du Pont stock. That meant that the
sale qualified as a
dividend, at least literally. Congress
attempted to close down
the scheme with amendments to the
dividends received deduction
in 1997. /45/ It would have been nice if
the IRS had had the
chance to go to Congress before, rather
than after, the Seagram
scheme.
b. Cheshire-cat hybrid entities.
Treasury's announcement
that it will ignore LLCs at the
taxpayer's election has opened a
slew of tax reduction opportunities in
foreign tax planning. For
example, assume a U.S. corporation pays
an expense to an LLC
that pays dividends to Canadian
shareholders and the LLC is
ignored for U.S. purposes, but not for
Canadian tax purposes.
That means that the payments are
deductible payments for U.S.
purposes, but still dividends to Canadian
shareholders. Under
the U.S.-Canada treaty, the payment is
deductible by the U.S.
corporation and exempt from tax to
Canadian shareholder. /46/
Congress took away this specific example
of such planning in the
1997 act, but Congress prevented Treasury
from acting against
another set of arrangements using hybrid
Cheshire cat entities
in 1998. /47/ Any inconsistent treatment
of an entity by U.S.
and foreign taxing authorities means that
there will be
anomalies that can be exploited.
c. MIPS and Cheshire-cat debt. The
optimal world for a
corporation is to be able to report a
financial instrument as
debt for tax purposes, so that interest
accrued is deductible,
while avoiding having the instrument
treated as debt on the
balance sheet for nontax accounting or
credit rating purposes.
The combination of debt for tax and
equity for nontax is
irresistible, and it will grow to rule
the world. /48/ The
specific lines of the tax and nontax
treatment do not matter.
Any inconsistency can be exploited.
d. Artificial losses from allocations.
The subchapter K
partnership rules often act as chemical
plants creating
artificial tax losses and distilling them
out for U.S.
corporations. A tax-exempt partner is
allocated large amounts of
taxable income or gain. That yields lots
of losses for the other
partner, a U.S. corporation. /49/ The
U.S. losses are
artificial, far in excess of the cash the
U.S. corporation has
ever invested or could lose. /50/ The
variations on the idea are
infinite. For individuals, the passive
activity limitations have
so far contained the use of artificial
losses to manageable
bleeding, but large corporations are not
subject to the section
469 passive activity limitations.
e. Astronomical basis. The
contribution and redemption
rules often shift basis of one
shareholder onto another. If one
shareholder is a foreign taxpayer who can
get basis from taxable
income or gain without paying tax, then
basis can be created for
the foreign shareholder and shifted to
the U.S. corporate
shareholder. /51/ The losses are once
again artificial, far in
excess of any cash the U.S. corporation
has ever invested or
could lose, but denying the losses
requires cutting through
the formal rules to the underlying
economic substance.
f. Deducting debt repayments: step
down preferred.
Repayment of principal is not supposed to
generate a tax
deduction, but REITs get deductions for
dividend distributions
and repayment of principal can be
disguised as if it were just
an ordinary dividend. The REIT then has
lots of deductions that
can shelter unrelated operating income.
/52/
________________________________________________________________________________
The above sample is just
one list of loophole schemes that have been found and publicized in the last
few years. The sampled transactions are obviously just the tip of the iceberg.
What about the deals that Lee Sheppard never heard about and never wrote about
in Tax Notes? She can't have seen everything. Any fair sample of the
budget-busting transactions would give a sound basis for paranoia. If the
Treasury Department thinks that the soundness of the tax system is being tested
every day by extraordinarily vicious and energetic enemies, that is not a
misperception of reality.
40 It is also extraordinarily hard to see what screen for
registration would catch all of the abuses in the sample while letting through
only the correctly reported routine transactions. Treasury might ask on a
registration form that taxpayers tell whether the transaction was reported
differently to some foreign tax authority, or to some other agency of the U.S.
government or on GAAP statements or credit ratings. Treasury might ask whether
and when tax deductions exceed cash lost. Still, a broad overall net, such as
the all-encompassing 'significant purpose to reduce tax' test, does seem to be
needed to catch all of the budget-busting abuses. A precise definition of abuse
or loophole is hopeless. Taxpayers would plan right around it, as the tide
moves around a post. A net narrower than 'significant purpose' to reduce tax
would miss some abuses and that is too bad for the country.
41 An automatic rule, like the significant purpose test, is also
required by the procedural posture in which the scope of registration must be
determined. Section 6111 requires the promoter to register or face penalties
before there has been a judicial resolution of any issue. When the promoter is
deciding whether to register or face penalties, there is no chance to make
subtle distinctions as to what might be an abuse or a loophole. You cannot
apply a sophisticated facts and circumstances test when there is no judge to
make the determination. Congress adopted the automatic or semi-automatic
significant-purpose rule test because it had to have a bright-line rule that
could be applied and enforced on the basis of instructions on a tax return, but
no judicial participation. A bright-line rule, as required by the procedural
posture, does allow for exemptions or exceptions, but both the exemptions and
the general rule for registrations must be stated as automatic rules.
42 Treasury has the authority to require registration whenever
there is a confidentiality agreement and $100,000 fees, but there needs to be
some exceptions for administrative convenience. If a taxpayer invests in
vanilla municipal bonds, routinely tax-exempt under section 103, for example,
the IRS could not deny the exemption and should not even try. No one buys
tax-exempt bonds except to avoid tax. The pretax interest coupons a municipal
bond gives are below the going interest rate so that no one buys them, except
to reduce tax and maximize after-tax yield. The $100,000 fee level should work
to filter out most of the routine, unchallengeable schemes, except that it will
not always be clear whether the fee went for cutting edge tax advice or just
for administrative or nontax issues. Still if it is clear beyond a shadow of a
doubt that the transaction is unchallengeable, Treasury might as well save
everybody the work of registration by issuing an exemption. If the tax
advantages are clearly within the statutory mandate and Congress is unlikely to
change the law, then the tax advantage is not an abuse under current law or
under law that Congress might adopt and Treasury can exempt it from
registration. Sometimes in a computer Key Word in Context search, the search
generates too many hits and one has to refine the Key Word in Context search in
midstream to stop so many false positives getting caught up in the search
description. So Treasury can refine its registration questions, with
experience, once it has studied what is out there. The way to handle the
problem in regulations is to provide that the IRS may exempt future
transactions from registration by Revenue Procedures issued from time to time.
43 Treasury and the IRS should, however, be very cautious in
granting exemptions from registration. It is as hard to define what is not an
abuse or not a loophole, as it is to define what is an abuse or a loophole.
Until Treasury studies what it catches in the net, the variety of tax-avoidance
schemes makes it difficult to see a priori whether it is an abuse. When you
refine a Key Word in Context search, you do so to get rid of the chaff of
irrelevant cases, but in narrowing the search some true gems are inevitably
lost as well. Some section 351 transactions, for example, are above reproach
and some are terrible shifting basis abuses in which the U.S. corporation ends
up formally with a basis far in excess of
any real investment. Some debt instruments are vanilla instruments,
entitled to an interest deduction without question, and some instruments
labeled 'debt' represent a new hybrid that will turn billions of dollars of
corporate stock into debt. Even a municipal bond might seem to be a vanilla
unchallengeable instrument at first glance, but turn out in fact to be a new
budget-buster scheme to avoid the arbitrage bond or industrial development bond
restrictions.
44 The regulations or early revenue procedures might well exempt
transactions from registration if the taxpayers are seeking a private letter
ruling: the private letter ruling process is probably sufficient in most cases
to protect Treasury's interest. Treasury should, similarly, look kindly on
claims for exemption from registration filed with a registration statement that
explains the tax advantages. On the other hand, Treasury has no pressing
administrative need to create big gaps in the net because Treasury will not be
swamped with registration statements from section 6111(d). Promoters will avoid
section 6111(d) if it matters, just by avoiding proprietary confidentiality
agreements.
45 Opponents of the shelter registration rules have argued that
registration might impede 'clearly permissible' tax minimization. /53/ 'Tax
minimization,' however, is just a synonym for 'tax avoidance,' /54/ so that the
statutory term 'tax avoidance' covers 'tax minimizations' completely. The
statute defines both 'evasion' and 'avoidance' as a shelter and so on the face
of the statute, some permissible tax reductions will be subject to
registration. The registration remedy was designed so that Treasury would have
a chance to find and close even those loopholes that are apparently available
under a technical reading of current law. If a loophole is going to be a budget
buster, Treasury needs to get a Distant Early Warning even if the loophole
might comply with current law. One can also not tell whether an arrangement is
'clearly permissible' when registration must be decided, because the promoter
must decide whether to register or face penalty long before the litigation over
the legitimacy of the loophole has reached its final determination. The section
6111 preregistration also serves to give notice to the IRS even for some cases
that the IRS is simply not going to win. Certainly if the registration in fact
would make a difference to the outcome of any big-money dispute, because it
lets the IRS understand the scheme and prepare for it, that is a pretty good
reason for requiring the arrangement to be registered in advance.
________________________________________________________________________________
FOOTNOTES
________________________________________________________________________________
/1/ Section 6662(d)(2)(C) as amended by Taxpayer Relief Act of
1997, section 1028(c) (defining 'tax shelter' as a plan or arrangement for
which a significant purpose is avoidance or evasion of any tax). Section
references are to the Internal Revenue Code of 1986, as amended, and the
regulations thereunder, except as otherwise noted.
/2/ Section 7525 added by the Internal Revenue Service
Restructuring and Reform Act of 1998, section 3411.
/3/ Section 6111(d) added by the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997,
section 2014.
/4/ See, e.g., Harry Graham Balter, Tax Fraud and Evasion
section 2.03, at 2-6 (1976) (saying that tax evasion connotes attempt to reduce
tax by unlawful means, while avoidance connotes the 'same ends by lawful
means.'); accord, Borris Bittker and Lawrence Lokken, 1 Federal Taxation of
Income Estates and Gifts para. 4.3.2 (2d ed. 1989). See Randolph Paul,
'Restatement of Tax Avoidance,' Studies in Federal Taxation 104 (1937)
(collecting numerous authorities to effect that tax avoidance by legal means is
permissible).
/5/ See, e.g., Dodge v. Ford Motor Co., 204 Mich. 459, 507, 170
N.W. 668,684 (1919) (corporation is organized and carried on primarily for the
profit of its shareholders); American Law Institute, Principles of Corporate
Governance section 2.01 (1974) (objective of a corporation is to enhance
corporate profit and shareholder gain).
/6/ Section 269(a) (acquisition made for the principal purpose
of tax avoidance); section 269A (items from personal service company may be
reallocated if the principal purpose of company was tax avoidance). The
Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, section 1028, replaced the phrase 'the principal
purpose' with the phrase 'significant purpose' in section 6662(d)(2)(C)(iii)
(accuracy-related penalties).
/7/ See, e.g., section 302(c)(2)(B) (redemption may be tested
ignoring constructive ownership of shares in some circumstances if the
acquisition was not made with 'one of the principal purposes' being avoidance
of federal income tax), section 467(b)(4)(B) (landlord may be required to
accrue rent if 'a principal purpose' of lease in which rent increased was tax
deferral); Treas. reg. section 1.704-2(b) (1995) (antiabuse rules triggered by
tax avoidance being 'a principal purpose').
/8/ James W. Pattillo, 'The Concept of Materiality in Financial
Reporting' (Financial Executive Research Foundation 1976) (finding 5-10 percent
to be a widely accepted rule of thumb to define materiality). But see Financial
Accounting Standards Board, Statement of Concepts No. 2, paras. 123-137,
161-170 (1980) (emphasizing that materiality level depends on the
context).
/9/ Lynch v. Commissioner, 273 F.2d 861, 972 (2d Cir. 1955)
(step-transaction doctrine used to deny interest deduction on grounds debt was
a sham).
/10/ Conference Committee Report, HR Conf. Rep. No. 105-599 at
89 (1998).
/11/ See, e.g., Blanchard v. Bergeron, 489 U.S. 87, 98-99 (1989)
(Scalia, J., concurring.); Thompson v. Thompson, 484 U.S. 174, 192 (1987)
(Scalia, J., concurring) (stating that legislative history is a 'frail
substitute for a bicameral vote upon the text of a law and its presentment to
the President'). See W. David Slawson, 'Legislative History and the Need to
Bring Statutory Interpretation Under the Rule of Law,' 42 Stan. L. Rev. 383
(1992).
/12/ Accord, Frank Easterbrook & Larry R. Fischel, The
Economic Structure of Corporate Law 38 (1991) (arguing that law should attach
prices to social costs, while expecting managers to maximize the wealth of
shareholders, instead of expecting managers to have mixed loyalties).
/13/ According to IRS figures the corporate tax gap was $33
billion in 1992. George Guttman, 'Increasing Voluntary Compliance to Over 90
Percent Is Unlikely,' Tax Notes, Apr. 11, 1994, p. 146 at 147.
/14/ U.S. Senate Budget Committee Majority Staff, Senate Budget
Committee Estimates Tax Gap, Tax Notes, Feb. 13, 1995, p. 1000 (saying that
there was a 50 percent growth in the corporate tax gap from 1981 to 1992, with
large corporations identified as having a 79.2 percent increase compared with
the 2.4 percent increase for small corporations.)
/15/ Martin Sullivan, 'Is Taxpayer Cheating Up or Down? Nobody
Knows,' Tax Notes, June 2, 1997, p. 1177.
/16/ Joe Bankman, 'The New Market for Corporate Tax Shelters,'
Ernst & Young Tax Policy Seminar at Georgetown Law Center (April 3, 1998),
-- Tax L. Rev. -- (forthcoming 1999).
/17/ William J. Stuntz, 'Law and the Christian Story,' 78 First
Things 28 (Dec. 1997) (The author begins the next paragraph saying 'I am, of
course, exaggerating. After all, the IRS does manage to collect a lot of
taxes.').
/18/ Section 6662(d)(2)(B)(i).
/19/ Section 6662(d)(2)(B)(ii).
/20/ Section 6662(d)(2)(C)(ii).
/21/ The classical formulation is Michael Allingham & Agnar
Sandmo, 'Income Tax Evasion: A Theoretical Analysis,' J. of Pub. Econ. 325
(Nov. 1972).
/22/ Section 7525 added by the Internal Revenue Service
Restructuring and Reform Act of 1998, section 3411(a).
/23/ Section 7525(b).
/24/ By reference to section 6662(2)(C)(iii).
/25/ Steve R. Johnson, 'Tax Advisor-Client Privilege: An Idea
Whose Time Should Never Come,' Tax Notes, Feb. 23, 1998, p. 1041 at 1043.
/26/ Lee A. Sheppard, 'What Tax Advice Privilege?' Tax Notes,
July 6, 1998, p. 9. /
/27/ See 'DOJ Seeks Reversal of Determination Allowing Attorney-
Client Privilege,' Tax Notes, July 13, 1998, p. 205.
/28/ Section 7625(a)(2).
/29/ Accord, Paul R. Rice, 'The Tax Practitioner Privilege: A
Sheep in Wolf's Clothing,' Tax Notes, Aug. 3, 1998, p. 617 (saying that the
exceptions destroy the privilege).
/30/ Burgess Raby and William Raby, 'Work-Product Doctrine and
the CPA,' Tax Notes, Mar. 9, 1998, p. 1289 at 1291, quoting a letter from one
Calvin Johnson to the SEC saying that the SEC needs to intervene in the
deliberations over section 7525 to protect the audit function. See letter,
Calvin H. Johnson to Chairman Arthur Levitt (Feb. 5, 1998), 98 TNT 39-44,
(arguing that if CPA firm begins to think of itself as business confidant it
will cease to serve the investing public).
/31/ See, e.g. Fred C. Zacharias, 'Rethinking Confidentiality,'
74 Iowa L. Rev. 351 (1989) (arguing that empirical study implies that strict
attorney-client confidentiality goes too far).
/32/ Section 6111(a).
/33/ See, e.g., U.S. Treasury Department, General Explanations
of the Administration's Revenue Proposals, at 81 (February 1997). Accord, U.S.
Treasury Department, General Explanations of the Administration's Revenue
Proposals, at 116 (March 1996).
/34/ See Notice 97-21, 1997-11 IRB 9 (step-down preferred stock
deals); Notice 95-53, 1995-2 C.B. 334 (lease stripping transactions); Notice
90-56, 1990-2 C.B. 344 (contingent payment installment sales); Notice 89-21,
1989-1 C.B. 651 (prepaid interest rate swaps).
/35/ Section 6111(c). Tax credits were translated into deduction
of (assumed) equivalent value.
/36/ The penalty for failure to register a shelter falling under
section 6111(d) is penalty equal to the greater of $10,000 or half of all the
fees paid to all promoters of the tax shelter for offerings before the shelter
is registered. If failure to file is intentional, then the penalty is raised to
the greater of $10,000 or 75 percent of all fees paid before registration
section 6707.
/37/ Section 6111(d)(2)(B).
/38/ Section 6111(d)(2)(A).
/39/ See, e.g, Edmund Kitch, 'The Nature and Function of the
Patent System,' 20 J. of Law and Econ. 265 (1977); Richard A. Epstein, 'Luck,'
6 Social Phil. & Policy 17, 26-28 (1988). See Tom Bethell, The Noblest
Triumph: Property and Prosperity Through the Ages (1998) (arguing that private
property rights are the 'noblest triumph' and primary determinant of the wealth
of nations).
/40/ American Bar Association, Center for Professional
Responsibility, Model Rules of Professional Conduct (1995), Rule 1.6 (lawyer
duty not to reveal client information).
/41/ The shelters of the 1970s and 1980s often had large amounts
of income at the back end of the shelter, beyond the first five years of the
shelter. At the front end of the shelter, an investor got deductions in excess
of cash invested because deductions were based on the investor's deemed
liabilities. At the back end of the shelter, the investor would have capital
gain or ordinary income when the liabilities were satisfied or avoided. Still
investors commonly underreported the gain -- by the back end all the
accountants and lawyers had been fired -- and even more commonly, the
promoter's projections ignored the back end results so that the investor did
not think about them. The 2:1 ratio of tax deductions to cash invested in the
first five years was thus not technically the real point at which tax benefits
offset an invested dollar, but investors acted as if it were.
/42/ Section 6111(d)(1)(C).
/43/ Joseph Bankman, supra note 13, at 27 (suggesting raising
the threshold to a $2,000,000 fee).
/44/ Evelyn F. Gregory, 27 B.T.A. 223 (1932), rev'd sub nom
Gregory v. Helvering, 69 F.2d 809 (2d Cir. 1934), aff'd 293 U.S. 463
(1933).
/45/ See, e.g., David Stewart, et al., 'Extraordinary Dividends
after TRA '97,' 25 J. of Corp. Taxation 252 (1998).
/46/ Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, Pub. L. No. 105-34, section
1054 enacting section 894 to deny treaty benefits to certain payments through
hybrid entities.
/47/ See Lee A. Sheppard, 'Notice 98-11 Withdrawal: Who Won?'
Tax Notes, June 29, 1998, p. 1671. For other foreign tax credit schemes, see,
e.g., James M Peaslee, 'Economic Substance Test Abused: Notice 98-5 and the
Foreign Law Taxpayer Rule,' Tax Notes, Apr. 6, 1998, p. 79.
/48/ See, e.g, Edward D. Kleinbard, 'Lee Sheppard's Misguided
Attacks on MIPS,' Tax Notes, June 8, 1998, p. 1365 at 1367 (stating that MIPS
now represent a $90 billion market, and defending the tax deduction). See also
John Reid, 'MIPS Besieged: Solutions in Search of a Problem,' Tax Notes, Dec.
1, 1997, p. 1057 (defending MIPS).
/49/ See, e.g, ACM Partnership v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 1997-
115, Doc 97-6453 (130 pages), 97 TNT 44-17 (large artificial gain from
installment sale proration of basis rule was allocated to foreign partner yielded
large artificial loss to U.S. corporate partner); Notice 90-56, 1990-2 C.B. 344
(similar contingent payment installment sales); Lee Sheppard, 'Hero of the Day:
Laro Saves the Corporate Income Tax,' Tax Notes, Mar. 17, 1997, p. 1382 (giving
Judge Laro credit for saving the corporate tax base in ACM Partnership); Lee A.
Sheppard, 'Colgate and Merrill Lynch Will Fight ACM Decision,' Tax Notes, May
19, 1997, p. 887.
/50/ See Treas. reg. section 1.165-1(b) (1959) (providing that
only bona fide loss is allowable and that substance and not form shall govern
in determining a deductible loss).
/51/ See, e.g., Joseph Bankman, supra note 13, at 2 (describing
scheme involving contribution of built-in loss property to domestic
corporation); Lee A. Sheppard, 'Importation of Built-In Losses and Devolution,'
Tax Notes, Apr. 13, 1998, p. 148 (explaining variations of artificial losses
through overstated basis); Lee A. Sheppard, 'Treasury Battles Importation of
Foreign Built-In Losses,' Tax Notes, Mar. 16, 1998, p. 1353; David Friedel,
'The Labyrinth of Section 304 and 1059 -- New Fictions Create Real Questions,'
89 J. of Taxation 79, 91 (Aug. 1998) (concluding that changes preclude most
mischievous basis shifting).
/52/ Notice 97-21,1997-11 IRB 9 (preferred stock that left only
immaterial amount after a normal debt term did not generate dividend deduction
for a REIT). See Lee A. Sheppard, 'Treasury Steps on Step- Down Preferred,' Tax
Notes, Mar. 3, 1997, p. 1102.
/53/ See Mark H. Ely and Evelyn Elgin, 'New Tax Shelter
Penalties Target Most Tax Planning,' Tax Notes, Dec. 8, 1997, p. 1153.
/54/ See, e.g., Harry Graham Balter, Tax Fraud and Evasion
section 2.01, at 2.1 (defining 'avoidance' as method to 'take advantage by
lawful means of all the opportunities provided by present law for reducing or
minimizing taxes.' (emphasis added)). See also authorities cited, supra note 4,
to the effect that 'tax avoidance' by legal means is permissible.
________________________________________________________________________________
END OF
FOOTNOTES
________________________________________________________________________________
________________________________________________________________________________
Further Reading
________________________________________________________________________________
________________________________________________________________________________
Surdell,
Steven M. 'ACM Partnership -- A New Text for Corporate Tax
Shelters?' 80 Tax Notes 1377-99 (June 9,
1997).
Bittker,
Boris I. 'Tax Shelters and Tax Capitalization or Does the
Early Bird Get a Free Lunch?' 28 National
Tax Journal 416-19
(1975).
Samwick,
Andrew A. 'Tax Shelters and Passive Losses After the Tax
Reform Act of 1986,' University of
Chicago Press and NBER 193-
233 (1996).
Howell,
H. Wayne. 'States Securities Regulation of Tax Shelters,' 38
National Tax Journal 339-43 (Sept. 1985).
Southworth,
Ann. 'Redefining the Attorney's Role in Abusive Tax
Shelters,' 37 Stanford Law Review (1985).
Gideon,
Kenneth W. 'Mrs. Gregory's Grandchildren: Judicial
Restrictions of Tax Shelters,' 5 Virginia
Tax Review 825-53
(Spring 1986).
Johnson,
Calvin H. 'Inefficiency Does Not Drive Out Inequity: Market
Equilibrium & Tax Shelters,' 71 Tax
Notes 377-87 (Apr. 15,
1996).
Sims,
Theodore S. 'Debt, Accelerated Depreciation, and the Tale of a
Teakettle: Tax Shelter Abuse
Reconsidered,' 42 UCLA Law Review
263-376 (Dec. 1995).